There are several methods available to inform funding decisions in health care. These include cost‑effectiveness, cost-utility, cost-minimisation and cost–benefit analysis (Table). They allow decision makers to assess the benefits of funding decisions relative to the cost. In Australia these methods are used by the Pharmaceutical Benefits Advisory Committee (PBAC) to meet the legislative requirements in making funding recommendations for drugs to government.
The different types of economic evaluation vary according to the types of costs and outcomes being compared. When evaluating drugs, a key consideration for an economic evaluation is the choice of the comparator or alternative drug. The PBAC currently defines a comparator as the ‘therapy that prescribers would most replace in practice’ with the proposed medicine.1 The choice of comparator is critical because when completing an economic evaluation we are essentially interested in the incremental costs and outcomes of the proposed new treatment over the comparator. For instance, if placebo is chosen as a comparator instead of an active treatment then the bar is set lower for determining the therapeutic advantage and, by extension, the economic argument for the new treatment. The choice of comparator thus influences the question being posed, such as whether the medicine is considered superior or non-inferior, and the type of economic evaluation to be used.
In general, a cost-minimisation analysis is used when two drugs are considered non-inferior in terms of health outcomes, such as drugs in the same therapeutic class and biosimilar drugs. Net costs are compared to establish the cheapest alternative. Recent examples of drugs listed via a cost-minimisation analysis include a vaccine for the prevention of diphtheria, tetanus and pertussis and an infliximab biosimilar.2
In contrast, a cost-effectiveness or cost-utility analysis is presented in tandem with a superiority argument. Net costs are compared to net health outcomes such as life-years or clinical parameters. A cost-utility analysis (considered a subset of cost-effectiveness analysis) compares net costs against net health outcomes as measured by the quality-adjusted life-year (QALY). As a cost-utility analysis provides a consistent unit of measure (incremental cost per QALY gained), comparisons can be made between funding options, and therefore this analysis is preferred by the PBAC. Tamoxifen,3 for the primary prevention of breast cancer, is a recent example of a drug listed via a cost-utility analysis. Conversely an example of a drug de-listed due to unacceptable cost-effectiveness (calculated via cost-utility analysis) was cinacalcet for the treatment of patients with end-stage renal disease receiving dialysis who have uncontrolled secondary hyperparathyroidism.4
A cost–benefit analysis considers costs and health outcomes in monetary units. Health outcomes can be converted to monetary units by calculating society’s willingness to pay to avoid poor health, or by calculating the cost of illness through lost wages or the cost of treatment. Although the PBAC does not generally accept cost–benefit analyses (without an accompanying cost-utility analysis), previous submissions have used this type of analysis to assist with determining an appropriate price.5